Journal Issue
Share
Article

Globalization Facts and Figures

Author(s):
Paul Masson
Published Date:
November 2001
Share
  • ShareShare
Show Summary Details

I. Introduction

Globalization is a phenomenon whose economic dimensions involve increases in the flows of trade, capital, and information, as well as mobility of individuals across borders. Even though it has received much attention in the last few years—indeed, an inordinate amount—it is by no means new. It has been argued that globalization has proceeded throughout the course of recorded history, though not in a steady or linear fashion.2 It has been driven in many cases by significant technological advances, and has, as such, been associated with the vast improvements in prosperity that the world has experienced in recent centuries.

While increased international trade and capital flows (relative to domestic activity) associated with globalization have been the source of an unprecedented rise in living standards around the world, neither the process of globalization nor the gains are guaranteed or automatic. On the contrary, there are numerous examples from the 20th century of countries limiting their exposure to foreign trade and capital. However, attempts to restrict the advance of globalization hamper individual countries’ abilities to share in the gains, and can have disastrous consequences when imposed on a global scale. An example is the generalized attempt to turn inward and cut off influences from the outside world that occurred during the period between the two world wars of the twentieth century.

Despite a general trend to increasing globalization in the post-1950 period, not all countries have benefited, nor have all citizens of a given globalizing country prospered. Those countries that have seen the greatest increases in per capita income have pursued outward oriented policies, rather than a policy of import substitution, and have put in place structural reforms to develop the institutions necessary for good governance and economic growth and to increase their economies’ flexibility. Strong growth gives governments the resources to improve the prospects of the poor. Since globalization, like technological change, produces both winners and losers within each country, it is important to put in place social safety nets to cushion the losers from the worst effects and more generally to put in place policies that equalize opportunities, including improved public education, health and security.

Finally, the international financial institutions have a crucial role in ensuring that globalization occurs in an orderly fashion. This role has become prominent with the financial crises that struck emerging markets in recent years; while the hardships resulting from these crises have far from erased the gains from openness in the countries affected, preventing such crises and alleviating their consequences would clearly be beneficial. In particular, the IMF must help to create a financial architecture that decreases the risk of crisis and eases the burden of adjustment on countries negatively affected by crises.

II. The Recent Experience of Globalization in Historical Perspective

It is instructive to compare the post-1950 period of globalization with the previous phase of strong globalization that occurred in the late 19th-early 20th centuries, because they are probably the two periods of strongest sustained output growth in world history (see Annex, World Economic Outlook, May 1997). The turn of the century also exhibited rapid growth in world trade, as the expansion of exports (3.5 percent per year) significantly outpaced that of real output (2.7 percent). The share of exports in world output reached a peak in 1913 that was not surpassed until 1970. Growth in trade occurred partly as a result of reduced tariffs, but more importantly was due to sharply falling transportation costs (Table 1) In the 50 years before World War I, there was a massive flow of capital from Western Europe to the rapidly developing countries of the Americas, Australia, and elsewhere. At its peak, the capital outflow from Britain reached 9 percent of GNP, and was almost as high in France, Germany, and the Netherlands. Capital importing countries, such as Canada, had current account deficits that reached 10 percent of GDP. These levels of net capital flows were favored by the fact that the world was on the gold standard which ensured convertibility and stable exchange rates. Migration was also very large during this period, with decadal migration in the 1880s, 1890s and 1900s equaling 5-7 percent of the population in several of the European countries sending emigrants, 4-9 percent in the United States, and much higher figures for other “new world” countries receiving immigrants (Baldwin and Martin, 1999).

Table 1.Transport Costs, 1830-1990
Ocean TransportAverage Air Transportation

Revenue per Passenger Mile

(in 1990 US$)
Wheat, Percent

of Production Costs
Ocean Freight

1920 = 100
183079
185076
188041
191027.5
1920100
1930650.68
1940670.46
1950380.30
1960280.24
1970290.16
1980250.10
1990300.11
Sources: Baldwin and Martin (1999); World Economic Outlook, May 1997, Table 11.
Sources: Baldwin and Martin (1999); World Economic Outlook, May 1997, Table 11.

The late 19th century–early 20th century period of globalization came to an end with the outbreak of world war, the unsuccessful attempt to revive the gold standard, and the great depression. Governments mistakenly thought that they could protect their citizens from an economic downturn abroad by raising tariffs and restricting imports. In fact, this just worsened the global depression and led to sharply reduced trade, plunging output, and pervasive unemployment. The post-1950 period of globalization and prosperity has been driven by the lowering of the barriers to trade and capital flows erected in the 1930s, as well as continued decline in transportation costs and, especially recently, communication costs.

The current period of globalization is in several respects less pronounced than the pre-World-War-I period. Net capital flows have been more modest. Capital exporting countries have rarely had current account surpluses that exceeded 5 percent of GDP, and similarly the sustainable deficits of net capital importing countries (now drawn from the ranks of so-called emerging market countries) have generally been below that figure. While transportation costs have seen a further fall (Table 1), it has been less dramatic than in the earlier period. And officially-sanctioned migration has been considerably more restricted than earlier, as the richer countries that are the preferred destination of migrants have limited their number. This in turn has led both to pent-up migration pressures and to illegal immigration (Hatton and Williamson, 2001).

While the nature of the technological innovations that characterize the recent period (such as those related to telecommunications, computers, and the Internet) is no doubt unique, the earlier period was also characterized by major inventions (such as the internal combustion engine, steamship, telephone, and telegraph) that decreased communication and transportation costs. As now, technological change was a major force for increasing the interdependence among countries, thus fuelling globalization. Conversely, globalization, in the form of the spread of information across borders, has allowed a far greater number of people to share in the benefits of those innovations.

III. Globalization in the Post-War Period

Since the Second World War, globalization has resumed, as the barriers to trade in goods and services, capital, and ideas that were imposed during the great depression and world conflict were rolled back, and technology has advanced, especially in the area of communications and computers (Table 2) The past fifty years have also seen a remarkable rise in living standards, as well as dramatic improvements in health and education (Table 3) While these advances have had other causes, including reconstruction after the wars, globalization has facilitated their spread throughout the world. For instance, medical advances have been pioneered in the richer countries, but improvements in health have also occurred in developing countries—indeed, to an even greater extent. Infant mortality rates declined by 40-50 per thousand from 1970-1999 in developing country regions, versus 13 per thousand on average in the developed countries. Life expectancy rose dramatically, as well. In China it essentially doubled (to 70 years) over 1960-99, while in India, it rose by 20 years, to 64 years (life expectancy rose in the United States from 70 to 77 years over the same period). Education has also shown a strong improvement in developing countries. For instance, adult illiteracy rates (Table 3) have declined by about 30 percentage points in China, Ghana, India, Korea and Mexico, over the past three to four decades. The advances in living standards, health, and education have occurred because flows of goods, capital and information have allowed poorer countries to use modern technology in local production and public services.

Table 2.Communication and Computer Costs, 1960-2000
Cost of a 3-minute

Telephone Call, New York to London
Price of Computers and

Peripheral Equipment

Relative to GDP deflator
(in 2000 US$)(2000 = 1000)
196060.421,869,004
197041.61199,983
19806.3227,938
19904.377,275
20000.401,000
Sources: World Economic Outlook, May 1997, Table 11, updated to 2000; U.S. Commerce Department, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Sources: World Economic Outlook, May 1997, Table 11, updated to 2000; U.S. Commerce Department, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Table 3:Infant Mortality, Life Expectancy, and Adult Illiteracy Selected Countries and Regions, 1960-99
19601970198019901999
China
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)13269423330
Life expectancy at birth (years)3662676970
Adult illiteracy rate (%)49352317
Ghana
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)131112946657
Life expectancy at birth (years)4549535758
Adult illiteracy rate (%)71564230
India
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)1511371169270
Life expectancy at birth (years)4351555964
Adult illiteracy rate (%)7664575248
Korea
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)824626128
Life expectancy at birth (years)5460677073
Adult illiteracy rate (%)2913742
Mexico
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)9373513629
Life expectancy at birth (years)5762677072
Adult illiteracy rate (%)382518129
United States
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)26201387
Life expectancy at birth (years)7073767677
Adult illiteracy rate (%)21<5<5<5
Sub-Saharan Africa
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)13211410792
Life expectancy at birth (years)5152
Adult illiteracy rate (%)5043
East Asia and Pacific
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)77563535
Life expectancy at birth (years)6868
Adult illiteracy rate (%)2417
South Asia
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)1381209375
Life expectancy at birth (years)5861
Adult illiteracy rate (%)5451
Latin America and Caribbean
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)82604831
Life expectancy at birth (years)6869
Adult illiteracy rate (%)1513
Developed / High Income Countries
Infant mortality rate (per 1,000 live births)191386
Life expectancy at birth (years)7777
Adult illiteracy rate (%)
Source: World Development Indicators and World Development Report (various issues), World Bank.
Source: World Development Indicators and World Development Report (various issues), World Bank.

Clearly, real GDP growth in a country creates the means necessary for sharing the benefits of globalization among the population: only with growth are the poor able to lift themselves from poverty. Cross country evidence suggests that incomes of the poorest 20 percent of the population increase roughly one-for-one with average per capita income: growth is good for the poor (Dollar and Kraay, 2001).

The evidence is strong that openness to international trade is a key ingredient of more rapid growth. The World Bank has classified countries on the basis of the extent that they increased trade relative to income in the post-1980 period. The top third of developing countries classified on this basis—termed the “new globalizes”—lowered average import tariffs by 34 percentage points and increased trade relative to income by 104 percent. In these countries, per capita income grew by 3.5 percent per annum in the 1980s and 5 percent in the 1990s. In contrast, the remaining developing countries—termed the “marginalized countries”—lowered tariffs by only 11 percentage points and saw little or no growth in GDP per capita in the post-1980 period (World Bank, 2001).

Figure 1 gives some illustrations of the dramatic increases in per capita income in constant prices that have accompanied the expansion of trade of those countries which have globalized. For instance, Korea has seen an average annual increase of 6.0 percent, doubling real incomes every 12 years, and increasing them more than 8-fold between 1960 and 1999. China has seen average growth of 5.1 percent over that period. In Africa, Ghana saw its per capita income increase steadily after 1983, once its policy of inward focus and declining openness was reversed. Mexico has seen a dramatic increase in openness since 1970 and substantial per capita income growth, albeit punctuated by economic crises. Other countries in Asia, Africa and Latin America that opened their economies also experienced faster growth than in the advanced countries.

Figure 1:Trade Openness1 and Real Per Capita Income

1/ Sum of Exports and Imports, divided by GDP.

The preponderance of empirical evidence suggests that promoting openness, and supporting it with sound domestic policies, leads to faster growth (Srinivasan and Bhagwati, 1999). The earlier strategy of attempting to grow through import substitution—that is, by limiting ties with other economies—has been conclusively shown to have failed, as there are no successful cases of fast-growing countries that followed this strategy in the recent period (Krueger, 1978; Lindert and Williamson, 2001).

Studies of the effects of the most recent round of global trade liberalization, the Uruguay Round, bear this out. Reducing tariff and non-tariff barriers is estimated to have produced annual increases in global GDP (in 1992 dollars) of between $100-300 billion (with a few estimates below or above this range), which is 1½ to 5 times total aid flows to developing countries. Moreover—and contrary to the rhetoric of the protectionists—most of the gains accrue to the countries (including especially advanced countries) that offered the most concessions in the negotiations (Harrison et al., 1997; Whalley, 2000). As with technological change, however, not everyone gains from trade liberalization: as countries better exploit their comparative advantage, formerly protected sectors may shrink and their workers suffer. However, detailed studies of trade liberalizations suggest that the benefits are more than ten times the costs (Matusz and Tarr, 1999).

Capital market integration is another feature of globalization that has expanded substantially in recent years. Capital inflows contribute to growth by stimulating investment and promoting financial development. While capital flows to developing countries have been subject to volatility, foreign direct investment has exhibited the steadiest sustained growth (Figure 2).

Figure 2Developing Countries: Gross Capital Flows

(Percent of GDP)

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics: and IMF staff estimates.

FDI has clear benefits for host countries because it is often associated with transfers of technology as well as financing, and it tends to be more stable than other capital flows. Recent crises have pointed to the need to provide appropriate incentives for capital to stay in a country and not flee at the first sign of trouble. More generally, countries with more open capital accounts tended to grow faster in the 1980s and 1990s, although experience across countries has varied (Chapter IV, World Economic Outlook, October 2001). Another aspect of integration with international capital markets is openness to trade in financial services. Cross-country evidence indicates that opening domestic financial markets to foreign financial institutions brings significant increases in stability and efficiency (Litan et al., 2001). Entry by foreign banks tends to aid diversification of domestic risks, enhance competition and efficiency, and lower moral hazard (Mishkin, 2001).

IV. Problems and Policy Challenges Accompanying Globalization

While globalization generally brings benefits, it is also associated with problems which have raised legitimate concerns. Apart from cultural, environmental, and political issues, which are not discussed here, the two principal areas of concern are inequality (both within and across countries) and volatility (in financial markets and of economic activity). In particular, there has not been a narrowing of global income inequalities, either across countries or within a number of individual countries, and recent emerging market financial crises have brought home the risks of exposure to international capital markets. In these areas, there is scope for improving government policies and the operation of the international economy in order to widen access to the benefits of globalization.

Inequality

Global inequality has two dimensions: inequality across and within countries. While per capita income has grown for the world as a whole, not all countries have experienced satisfactory growth, so that the average per capita income across all countries (advanced and developing) has become more dispersed—despite convergence among the advanced countries (Pritchett, 1997). Moreover, within some countries, inequality has increased over the past two decades (Table 4). As a result, global income inequality (combining the effect of developments within and across countries) rose throughout much of the post-World-War-II period (and the previous century), though by some measures it seems to have at least stabilized since 1990 (Dollar, 2001).

Table 4:Income Inequality (Gini Index): Selected Countries
Year1950196019701980199019951997/98
Brazil57.657.859.660.1
China28.834.641.540.3
Ghana36.732.732.7
India35.532.630.431.529.629.737.8
Korea34.032.033.338.633.631.6
Mexico52.655.557.950.554.953.7
Poland25.824.826.233.0
Sweden33.427.332.432.525.0
United Kingdom25.325.124.932.3
United States36.034.834.135.237.845.040.8
Source: Dollar and Kraay Database on Income Inequality, World Bank; indices may not be comparable across countries, in particular because some are net of taxes while others are not.
Source: Dollar and Kraay Database on Income Inequality, World Bank; indices may not be comparable across countries, in particular because some are net of taxes while others are not.

The causes of increased inequality have given rise to vigorous debate. Within industrial countries, it is linked to the widening skill premium that is reflected in the increasing gap between wages of skilled and unskilled workers. This contributes to the increases in inequality in the United Kingdom and the United States, for instance (Table 4) Evidence suggests that it is technological change, not trade with lower-wage developing countries, that has driven that widening premium (Slaughter and Swagel, 1997; Krueger, 2000; Krugman, 2000). Therefore, there seems to be little support for the contention that increased openness and reduced barriers to trade have been a significant cause of widening inequality within advanced countries.

Moreover, as a group, per capita incomes across these countries have strongly converged over the past 50 years.

Within some developing countries, inequality has also increased even as income has grown for both rich and poor. Many factors can be expected to affect inequality, some of them specific to the countries concerned (such as wars and natural disasters) while others are more general (such as technological change, mentioned above), so it is wrong to try to link it solely to globalization. In China, opportunities in the rapidly developing cities have exacerbated the gaps between rural and urban incomes. However, those regions that were more open to international trade experienced a decline in urban-rural inequality, so globalization per se does not seem to have been the cause of greater inequality (Wei and Wu, 2001). In the transition economies in Central and Eastern Europe, widening inequality was an inevitable outcome of the return to a system of economic incentives and rewards. In some countries, however, high inequality may reflect lack of opportunity and the persistence of poverty, which can be the source of social conflicts that inhibit the achievement of adequate growth and development.

It seems likely that globalization in fact promoted convergence of per capita incomes between poor and rich countries. As discussed above, per capita income has grown faster in globalizing developing countries than in rich countries—5 percent versus 2.2 percent a year in the 1990s. By contrast, per capita incomes have barely grown in countries that did not globalize, increasing the gap with rich countries. The difference in performance thus accounts for the apparent lack of general convergence between rich and poor countries taken together. But the persistence of inequality across countries is a powerful force for migration to richer countries. Baldwin and Martin (1999) note that the earlier (pre-World-War-I) period of globalization saw lower formal barriers to migration and much larger flows. Nevertheless, formal barriers often prove ineffective, so this aspect of globalization will no doubt continue to be prominent as long as economic incentives for migration remain.

Volatility

The second major problem concerns the volatility in financial markets that openness to global capital markets seems to bring, and, more generally, the volatility of economic activity. The 1990s saw a series of financial crises affecting individual countries, regions, and even global financial markets. Recent international financial crises seem to be the result of home-grown vulnerabilities related dramatic declines in transportation coststo financial sector weaknesses, overvalued exchange rates, and unsustainable fiscal positions, often accompanied by volatile market sentiment and contagion effects from other countries. But the experience of these crises has been that they brought dramatic movements in exchange rates and current account balances that far exceeded any initial disequilibria, and were associated with severe economic contractions.

Another aspect of globalization, the spread of the information technology (IT) revolution, has strengthened real and financial linkages across countries (Chapter III, World Economic Outlook, October, 2001). The prices of IT goods have gone through large swings in recent years, and as a result a number of Asian countries and others have been exposed to high volatility in their export earnings. In addition, business cycles, flows of foreign direct investment, and stock price indices have become more synchronized as a result of the increasing importance of IT goods for many countries. Volatility derived from exposure to the global market for IT goods, combined with the uncertainty concerning underlying productivity growth (given the rapid pace of innovation in the IT sector), call for greater prudence in setting macroeconomic policies.

Policy Responses

Governments, with the help of the international financial institutions, need to address both of these problems. The persistence of poverty requires adequate social safety nets to mitigate negative effects on the most disadvantaged and government spending on public education, health, and security, that help to equalize opportunities. Tax competition (especially the tendency for the most mobile factor, capital, to flee high taxation) may, however, limit the scope for governments to raise revenue. The International Monetary Fund can contribute through financing associated with the PRGF and the HIPC Initiative in support of a coherent program of economic policies, and through technical assistance for capacity building to strengthen the institutional framework. Policies aimed at maintaining macroeconomic stability can help moderate the unemployment and wage losses associated with economic downturns, as well as the unfavorable effects of inflation, which has a disproportionately heavy impact on the poor.

Another important step is the further opening by rich countries of their markets to exports from developing countries by reducing tariff and non-tariff barriers and domestic subsidies (especially on agricultural goods, textiles, and clothing) so that the less developed countries can get the full benefits of the global trading system. Calls in rich countries for environmental and labor standards in developing countries are often presented as being motivated by a concern for limiting the adverse impact of globalization on poor countries. In fact, their effect would be to create barriers to the growth-creating trade that permits poor countries to narrow the gap with rich countries.

Improvements in the international financial architecture are aimed at decreasing the likelihood of crises and mitigating their costs. IMF initiatives in this area include mechanisms for private sector involvement, enhanced early warning systems, and the Contingent Credit Line facility. Though financial openness (once it has been achieved) brings important advantages, opening up an economy needs to be done in an orderly way and after strengthening domestic financial institutions through enhanced supervision, regulation, and transparency, and strengthening macroeconomic stability. The IMF can help governments make their financial systems more robust through implementation of standards and codes (including those related to monetary and fiscal policies and to data dissemination) and the Financial Sector Assessment Program.

In sum, globalization, though it needs to be managed properly, has widespread benefits, including for the least fortunate. With properly designed policies, it can be harnessed to reduce poverty while at the same time keeping financial market volatility in check. The alternative, to attempt to reverse the course of globalization, is likely to reduce global prosperity sharply, with unfavorable effects on rich and poor alike.

References

    BaldwinRichard and PhilippeMartin1999“Two Waves of Globalisation: Superficial Similarities, Fundamental Differences,”NBER Working Paper 6904.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    DollarDavid2001“Globalization, Inequality, and Poverty since 1980,”World Bankmimeo.

    DollarDavid and AartKraay2001“Growth is Good for the Poor,”World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 2587.

    HarrisonGlennThomasRutherford and DavidTarr1997“Quantifying the Uruguay Round”Economic JournalSeptember.

    HattonTimothy and JeffreyWilliamson2001“Demographic and Economic Pressure on Emigration out of Africa,”NBER Working Paper 8124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    KruegerAnne1978Liberalization Attempts and ConsequencesCambridge: Ballinger for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    KruegerAnne2000Trading Phobias: Governments NGOs and GlobalisationCentre for Independent Studies, St. Leonard’s,Australia.

    KrugmanPaul2000“Technology, Trade, and Factor Prices,”Journal of International EconomicsFebruary.

    LewisHoward and J. DavidRichardson2001“Why Global Commitment Really Matters!”Institute for International Economicsmimeo.

    LindertPeter and JeffreyWilliamson2001“Does Globalization Make the World More Unequal?”NBER Working Paper 8228.

    LitanRobertPaulMasson and MichaelPomerleanoeds.2001Open Doors: Foreign Participation in Financial Systems in Developing CountriesWashington: Brookings.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    MatuszSteven and DavidTarr1999“Adjusting to Trade Policy Reform,”Policy Research Working Paper No. 2142 World Bank.

    MishkinFrederick2001“Financial Policies and the Prevention of Financial Crises in Emerging Market Countries,”NBER Working Paper 8087.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    O’RourkeKevin and JeffreyWilliamson2000“When Did Globalization Begin?”mimeoHarvard University.

    PritchettLant1997“Divergence, Big Time,”Journal of Economic Perspectives 11: 3–18.

    SlaughterMatthew and PhillipSwagel1997“The Effect of Globalization on Wages in the Advanced Economies” Staff Studies for the World Economic OutlookDecember.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    SrinivasanT.N. and JagdishBhagwati1999“Outward-Orientation and Development: Are the Revisionists Right?”Yale University Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 806.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    WeiShang-Jin and YiWu2001“Globalization and Inequality: Evidence from within China”mimeoGeorgetown University and IMF.

    WhalleyJohn2000“What Can the Developing Countries Infer from the Uruguay Round Models for Future Negotiations?”Policy Issues in International Trade and Commodities Study Series No. 4New York: United Nations.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    World Bank2001“Globalization, Growth and Poverty: Facts, Fears, and an Agenda for Action,” draft for commentsJuly.

1I am grateful to a number of colleagues within the IMF for comments. The paper was initiated in response to a request from Anne Krueger, and benefited from early discussions with Ashoka Mody and the research assistance of Saji Thomas.
2O’Rourke and Williamson (2000) however argue that globalization only began in the 19th century, following dramatic declines in transportation costs.

Other Resources Citing This Publication